Oligopoly Competition

Oligopoly Competition

Demand Analysis under Oligopoly Competition

The demand curves in oligopoly markets are influenced by the level of pricing interdependence among firms. When collusion exists in a market, the aggregate market demand curve is divided among the individual producers. In contrast, each firm faces its own demand curve in non-colluding market scenarios. Additionally, the demand characteristics in non-colluding oligopoly markets are shaped by the pricing strategies employed by the participating firms.

Three primary pricing strategies include Pricing interdependence, the Cournot assumption, and the Nash equilibrium.

Price Interdependence

In oligopolies, price interdependence means that firms’ pricing actions are linked. In these markets, it’s often assumed that competitors will lower prices to keep their customers and avoid raising prices to lure customers away from rivals.

The idea is that by matching a competitor’s lower price, the company won’t see a drop in customer interest. On the other hand, by not raising prices like another company, they can pull in customers from the company that did.

Customers of a firm are highly responsive to price increases when its competitors offer lower prices. On the other hand, customers become less responsive to price decreases because the firm’s rivals are likely to match its price changes.

As a result, there are two different demand structures:

  1. One for price increases.
  2. Another for price reductions.

Note that each demand curve will have its own marginal revenue. Denote the demand and marginal revenue curve by \(D_{P\uparrow}\) and \({MR}_{P\uparrow}\) when the price increases and by \(D_{P\downarrow}\) and \({MR}_{P\downarrow}\) when the prices fall. Consider the following diagram:

From the above diagram, the overall demand can be seen as \(D=D_{P\uparrow}+D_{P\downarrow}\). This oligopolistic pricing strategy leads to a kinked demand curve, where the two segments represent distinct competitor reactions to price changes. The kink in the demand curve creates two parts in the marginal revenue structure. One part is connected to price increases, and the other is related to price decreases.

Observe the following kinked demand curve in the Oligopoly market:

If the company has low marginal costs, labeled as \(MC_1\), the earlier rule of setting marginal revenue (MR) equal to marginal cost (MC) remains true even in an oligopoly. The marginal cost can increase to \(MC_2\) and \(MC_3\) before affecting the firm’s profit. If the \(MC_2\) curve intersects the space in the marginal revenue, the best price-output combo stays the same at the current price and initial output level.

The Cournot Assumption

Under the Cournot assumption, each firm determines its optimal production level, assuming that the output of other firms will remain unaltered. Their goal is to maximize profits while expecting the other firm to maintain a constant output in the future.

Cournot assumption makes pricing strategy easier as there’s no need to predict a competitor’s response. It offers a practical way to study actions in oligopoly markets. Consider the simplest oligopoly scenario: a duopoly with two firms. When in equilibrium, neither wishes to alter production based on the other’s output. Each company tries to maximize profits, thinking the other will maintain its current production level.

The Cournot strategy approach is believed to persist until both firms reach their long-run equilibrium. In this equilibrium, both output and price stabilize, and no changes in price or output can result in increased profits for either firm.

The Nash Equilibrium

The Nash equilibrium occurs when participants in a non-cooperative market choose strategies and stick to them, even after considering their opponents’ strategies.

In oligopoly markets, the Nash equilibrium is characterized by the fact that no firm in the oligopoly can increase its profits by unilaterally altering its pricing strategy. The basic assumption is that each participating firm does the best it can, considering the reactions of its rivals.

In other words, each firm expects the other firms to respond to any change made by competitors by doing their best under the changed circumstances.

In the oligopoly market, firms’ actions are interdependent and non-corporative, with each firm making decisions that maximize its own profits. In other words, the firms do not collude. Equilibrium is achieved when all firms are striving to do their best in their interest, considering the actions of their rivals.

Example: Illustrating Nash Equilibrium

Consider a duopoly with companies A and B. Both companies can change high or low prices for their products. The following table gives the amount of profits each company receives if it charges a high or low price:

 

The interpretation of the table is as follows: Consider the top left corner cell. The cell shows that when both companies offer the product at low prices, company A earns a profit of 60, and company B earns 80.

It is easy to see that both companies earn a maximum combined profits of 1,000 if both companies charge high prices.

Recall that according to Nash equilibrium, each firm behaves in its own best interest. In our case above, company B can improve its position by charging low prices when company A charges high prices. Specifically, in the lower left cell, company B earns a profit of 450 when company A charges a high price of 400.

Notice that company A can earn a maximum profit of 600 only if company B agrees to charge a high price. However, this is not in Company B’s best interest because it can still earn a profit of 450 by charging lower prices.

Collusion in Oligopoly Markets

In oligopolistic industries, the conditions promote collusion as there are only a few competitors, and their pricing behavior is interdependent. Collusion is motivated by several factors, such as the potential for increased profits, the desire to reduce uncertainty in cash flow, and the opportunity to create barriers that discourage new entrants.

When firms openly and formally establish collusive agreements, they form a cartel. Six factors significantly influence the chances of successful collusion:

  1. The number and size distribution of sellers: Collusion is more likely to succeed in markets with a small number of firms or when one firm dominates the market.
  2. The similarity of the products: Collusion has a higher chance of success when the products are homogeneous and indistinguishable.
  3. Cost structure: Successful collusion is more probable when the participating firms have similar cost structures.
  4. Order size and frequency: Collusion is more likely to be successful when orders are frequent, regular, and of relatively small sizes.
  5. The strength and severity of retaliation: The fear of severe retaliation discourages firms from breaking collusive agreements.
  6. The degree of external competition: Collusive agreements have higher chances of success when external competitors face higher production costs.

In oligopolistic markets, another notable decision-making strategy is the first-mover advantage in the Stackelberg model. This model assumes sequential decision-making, where the leader firm selects its output first, and then the follower firm chooses after observing the leader’s output. The leader firm gains an advantage by being the first mover in this scenario.

Demand, Supply Analysis under Oligopoly Competition

Just like in monopolistic competition, the oligopoly firm lacks a well-defined supply function. It’s impossible to ascertain the oligopolist’s best output and price without considering the demand conditions and competitors’ moves. Still, the oligopolist possesses a cost function that indicates the optimal supply level. Thus, the previously stated rule remains true: The output level maximizing profit occurs where MR = MC.

The price charged by the oligopolist is determined by what the consumers are willing to pay. Therefore, the equilibrium price results from the demand curve, while the output levels result from the association between the MR and the MC.

A dominant firm in an oligopoly market is one that has greater capacity, a lower cost structure, is a pioneer in the market, or has secured greater customer loyalty. As such, the dominant firm becomes the price maker with similar powers as monopolists.

The other firms in the market follow the pricing strategies of the dominant firm. The followers cannot undermine the dominant firm because the leader has a lower cost of production. Surprisingly, the price followers would rather charge a higher price than the dominant firms’ price.

Optimal Price and Output in Oligopoly Markets

There is no optimum price and output analysis that applies to all oligopoly market scenarios. The interdependence of the few firms in an oligopoly leads to an intricate range of pricing options, which vary based on the specific market conditions.

For instance, in a kinked demand curve, the optimum price is the prevailing price at the kink on the demand function. However, when a dominant market exists, the optimum price is determined at a point where MR = MC. The profit-maximizing price is based on the output position of the part of the demand function faced by the dominant firm.

Factors Affecting Long-Run Equilibrium in Oligopoly Markets

In the long run, there is a possibility for economic profits in oligopoly markets. However, the market share of a dominant firm will decline in the long run. As is always the case, profits will attract more firms to enter the oligopoly market.

Over time, marginal costs incurred by entrant firms fall due to the adoption of more efficient production methods. Likewise, the profitability of the dominant firm declines. The reactions of entrant firms are included in the optimal pricing strategy.
Some firms may decide to incorporate innovation as a way of maintaining market leadership. For example, Shell’s gasoline is said to clean the engine valves and fuel injectors. However, these innovations are usually not very effective at maintaining the market share of the dominant firm.

Generally, an optimal pricing strategy, in the long run, incorporates the reactions of rival firms to changes in prices effected by competitors. However, history shows price wars are not beneficial, as market share gains are often fleeting. For instance, cutting prices to outdo rivals reduces overall earnings for everyone in the oligopoly.

Question

Which of the following is a factor that influences the chances of a successful collusion?

  1. Similarity in cost structures.
  2. Presence of a dominant firm.
  3. Infrequent, large order sizes.

Solution

The correct answer is A.

Successful collusion is more probable when the participating firms have similar cost structures.

B is incorrect. Collusion is more likely to succeed in markets with a small number of firms or when one firm dominates the market.

C is incorrect. Collusion is more likely to be successful when orders are frequent, regular, and of relatively small sizes.

Shop CFA® Exam Prep

Offered by AnalystPrep

Featured Shop FRM® Exam Prep Learn with Us

    Subscribe to our newsletter and keep up with the latest and greatest tips for success
    Shop Actuarial Exams Prep Shop Graduate Admission Exam Prep


    Sergio Torrico
    Sergio Torrico
    2021-07-23
    Excelente para el FRM 2 Escribo esta revisión en español para los hispanohablantes, soy de Bolivia, y utilicé AnalystPrep para dudas y consultas sobre mi preparación para el FRM nivel 2 (lo tomé una sola vez y aprobé muy bien), siempre tuve un soporte claro, directo y rápido, el material sale rápido cuando hay cambios en el temario de GARP, y los ejercicios y exámenes son muy útiles para practicar.
    diana
    diana
    2021-07-17
    So helpful. I have been using the videos to prepare for the CFA Level II exam. The videos signpost the reading contents, explain the concepts and provide additional context for specific concepts. The fun light-hearted analogies are also a welcome break to some very dry content. I usually watch the videos before going into more in-depth reading and they are a good way to avoid being overwhelmed by the sheer volume of content when you look at the readings.
    Kriti Dhawan
    Kriti Dhawan
    2021-07-16
    A great curriculum provider. James sir explains the concept so well that rather than memorising it, you tend to intuitively understand and absorb them. Thank you ! Grateful I saw this at the right time for my CFA prep.
    nikhil kumar
    nikhil kumar
    2021-06-28
    Very well explained and gives a great insight about topics in a very short time. Glad to have found Professor Forjan's lectures.
    Marwan
    Marwan
    2021-06-22
    Great support throughout the course by the team, did not feel neglected
    Benjamin anonymous
    Benjamin anonymous
    2021-05-10
    I loved using AnalystPrep for FRM. QBank is huge, videos are great. Would recommend to a friend
    Daniel Glyn
    Daniel Glyn
    2021-03-24
    I have finished my FRM1 thanks to AnalystPrep. And now using AnalystPrep for my FRM2 preparation. Professor Forjan is brilliant. He gives such good explanations and analogies. And more than anything makes learning fun. A big thank you to Analystprep and Professor Forjan. 5 stars all the way!
    michael walshe
    michael walshe
    2021-03-18
    Professor James' videos are excellent for understanding the underlying theories behind financial engineering / financial analysis. The AnalystPrep videos were better than any of the others that I searched through on YouTube for providing a clear explanation of some concepts, such as Portfolio theory, CAPM, and Arbitrage Pricing theory. Watching these cleared up many of the unclarities I had in my head. Highly recommended.