European Options
European options only allow for the exercise of options at the expiry date,... Read More
As the underlying value determines the option payoff, if we know the outcome of the underlying, we know the value of the option. If the underlying is above the exercise price at expiration, then the payoff is ST – X for calls and zero for puts. The converse is true if the underlying is below the exercise price at expiration. The derivation of an option pricing model requires the specification of a model of random processes that describe the movements in the underlying.
A model with two possible outcomes is a binomial model. We start with the underlying at S0 and let the price move up to S1+ and down to S1–. We don’t know which outcome will occur, but we can assign probabilities. Assuming the probability of the move to S1+ is q, then the probability of moving to S1– is 1 – q.
$$
\begin{array}
\hline
{} & {\small q } & { S }_{ 1 }+ \\
{ S }_{ 0 } & {\Huge \begin{matrix} \diagup \\ \diagdown \end{matrix} } & {} \\
{} & {\small 1-q} & { S }_{ 1 }- \\
\end{array} $$
We then specify the returns implied by these moves up and down as factors u and d where u = S1+/S0 and d = S1–/S0.
$$
\begin{array}
\hline
{} & {\small q } & { S }_{ 0 }u \\
{ S }_{ 0 } & {\Huge \begin{matrix} \diagup \\ \diagdown \end{matrix} } & {} \\
{} & {\small 1-q} & { S }_{ 0 }d \\
\end{array} $$
We now consider a European call option with price co today and price c1+ and c1– at expiration. Assume we sell a call and buy h units of the underlying asset with portfolio value at inception V0 = hS0 – co. At time 1, the portfolio will either be worth:
$$ V_1^+ = hS_1^+ – c_1^+; or $$
$$ V_1^- = hS_1^- – c_1^-$$
If the portfolio was hedged then:
$$ V_1^+ = V_1^- $$
Which could be re-written as:
$$ hS_1^+ – c_1^+= hS_1^- – c_1^- $$
Where \(h = \frac{c_1^+ – c_1^- }{S_1^+ – S_1^-}\)
We also know that a perfectly hedged portfolio will earn the risk-free rate so:
$$ V_1^+ or \quad V_1^- = V_0(1+r)$$
We can finally obtain the formula for the option price as:
$$ c_0 = \frac{πc_1^+ + (1-π)c_1^-}{1+r}$$
Where \(π = \frac{1 + r – d}{u – d}\)
Having worked through all of the above, we have arrived at an equation for the value of a call option today, which takes the form of an expected future value (the numerator) discounted at the risk-free rate (the denominator). The volatility of the underlying is an important factor in determining the value of the option. If the volatility increases, the difference between S1+ and S1– increases which widen the range between c1+ and c1– leading to a higher option value.
We note that our actual probabilities of q and (1 – q) are not used, but instead, we have π and (1 – π), which are called risk-neutral probabilities. If the option is trading at a price too high relative to the formula, investors can sell the call, buy h shares of the underlying and earn a return in excess of the risk-free rate while funding the transaction by borrowing at the risk-free rate. This action will put downward pressure on the call price until it conforms with the model price once more.
Following the same methodology as above, we can derive a model for a put option as follows:
$$p_0 = \frac{πp_1^+ + (1-π)p_1^-}{1+r}$$
Where \(π = \frac{1 + r – d}{u – d}\)
Question
Which factors are the most relevant to determine an option’s value using a binomial pricing model?
A. The probability that the underlying will go up or down, the risk-free rate, and the initial value of the option
B. The risk-free rate, the volatility of the underlying, and the exercise price
C. The probability that the underlying will go up or down, the risk-free rate, and the risk-neutral probability
Solution
The correct answer is B.
The probability that the underlying will go up or down is not a factor in determining the price of an option using a binomial model because we derive it from the formula \(π = \frac{1 + r – d}{u – d}\).
The volatility of the underlying asset is an important factor, as is the risk-free rate, the risk-neutral probability, and the exercise price.